An intriguing example of how short term market considerations produce insane outcomes; what this means; and what we might do
(A blog that is too long and has a ridiculous title, because I want to put you off)
If you've walked along a British high street recently, it
will come as no surprise to you to learn that ‘vacancy rates’ – the proportion
of shops that are closed – are remarkably high.
Actually, if you live in London, you may not have
noticed. London, ever more de-coupled
from the real world and fuelled by funny money from “high net worth individuals”
and the “financial
and business services sector”, has a vacancy rate of around 7%.
Elsewhere, the years of austerity and falling real incomes
have taken their toll. Try Hartlepool,
or Newport, or Dudley: a third
of the shops are shut.
(It’s not just the high streets, either. Once upon a time there was a narrative in
which consumer spending was merely moving to those awful ‘out of town’ retail
parks: no
longer.)
It’s mainly to do with the fact that we all do all our
shopping via the interweb, of course, which means that, despite the televisual insights
of Mary Portas, the plangent efforts
of her dozen pilots
and the pronouncements from her state-gestated daughter the Future
High Streets Forum, the hard-arsed evidence suggests that things are only
going one way…
There are, of course, genuine and uplifting efforts to do
something about this: but they are not only small-scale, fragile and
fragmented; they are up against a hidden and very considerable barrier.
To you and I, and so far through this piece, a shop is a
shop is a shop: a rectangular space with stuff inside that you can, if you wish
and you have sufficient credit, buy.
However, there are those for whom a shop is not a shop, but
an ‘investment class’. Someone,
somewhere, owns the shop. Or, to be more
precise, an entity with an investment portfolio encompassing gilts, equities,
commodities, futures and so forth, also includes property assets within that;
and, within property, retail.
Now, I have to confess that I assumed that, since the kind
of people who would do such things are likely to be either the aforementioned “high
net worth individuals” and/or elite members of the “financial and business
services sector” (collectively, and henceforth, the “crazies”, if for no other
reason than it has been the relentless pursuit of their interests at the expense
of all others that has brought about the current craziness) that it would be
impossible to find out anything about what these people are up to.
But lo! A miracle! An august assembly – the Association of British
Insurers, the Association of Real Estate Funds, the British Council for
Offices, the British Council of Shopping Centres, the British Property Federation,
the Investment Property Forum, the Royal Institution of Chartered Surveyors and
the Urban land Institute (I just can’t be bothered with the hyperlinks I’m
afraid) – have published the marvellous “Property
Data Booklet 2012”, which contains some exceptionally useful ballast.
For example, all the commercial property in Britain has a
value of £717 billion. Who knew?
And, of this, £227 billion is retail property!
And, of this, about 5% is in the hands of private investors,
about 4% in the hands of charities and old-school trusts; and virtually all the
rest is in the hands of gigantic financial institutions (mainly pension funds)
and listed property companies.
Now here’s a thing.
It is a general and simple rule in economics that if the demand for
something falls while supply remains unchanged, the price declines. In the case of shops, this translates as: if
a landlord can’t lease a shop at a particular price, he or she should
progressively reduce the price until he or she can, in fact, let it.
From the occupier perspective, of course, the rent is a cost
that will need to be met out of income from selling whatever it is they sell;
so, to be sure, they’ll need to sell something.
And it also true that the rise in – for example – the number of charity
shops, who certainly pay lower rent than a commercial occupier might, is a sign
that some landlords, at least, are showing some flexibility in rents.
But – and here comes the catch – a commercial property
investor or pension fund expresses itself to the financial market through the
value of its assets; and the value of its retail assets is in large part a
function of the expected income stream over the lifetime of the asset; and is
calculated not on the basis of the actual
money it is receiving in rental income, but on the ‘rental value’ of the property, a presumed hypothetical value when everything is ‘normal’.
If you admit to the ‘market’ that your assets are worth,
say, 11% less than you said last year (11% being the current vacancy rate on
the average British high street) what do you suppose would happen? Yes: your share price would crash, your
investors would flee, your high-octane world among the crazies would come to a
torrid end.
So – it is less
costly for you to deliberately keep your row of shops on the high street empty, potentially
for years, than it would be to allow independent traders and other local worthies and weirdoes to occupy those shops on lower rents.
In short, a major reason for the current high vacancy rate
and the major block on the transformation of Britain’s high streets into new
areas of play, leisure and conviviality is the outcome of the perverse structure
of the reporting mechanisms in the UK’s financial system and, yet again, the interests
of those crazies.
They have to go.
Really.
[If there's a photo down here it was added
August 2017 as part of blog refresh. Photo is either mine or is linked to
where I found it. Make of either what you will.]
Comments